Growth of Latvia and Its Trade With EU Countries




Paper within  Development Economics
Authors:        Lauris Ancupans            810304
                     Sergejs Bolsakovs           750128
Tutor:           Börje Johansson
Jönköping     April, 2000

Table of Contents
1   Introduction.................................................................................. 1
2   Theoretical Outlook: Trade and Growth................................. 2
3   Latvia and EU: Trade Relations................................................ 8
3.1         Trade of Latvia by groups of countries......................................................... 8
3.2         The analysis of the structure of Latvian export and import ................... 13
4   Trade and Growth in Latvia..................................................... 19
5   Conclusion................................................................................. 20
References....................................................................................... 21
Appendices...................................................................................... 22

1    Introduction

The end of the 20th century has been quite eventful. The European customs union was established in 1968. In 1992 Maastricht Treaty  was signed which extended European cooperation. Dissolution of Soviet Union occurred in 1991. Latvia  as well as Estonia and Lithuania after 51 year of occupation regain their independence. Since that Latvia started its way toward market economy and democracy. European Union (EU) is an active supporter of these processes.
The liberalisation of Latvia led to trade relations with already existing market economies. It is obvious that such small countries like Latvia need international trade  and integration with the rest of the world to survive and prosper. In 1991 staying on the cross-road Latvia had three ways to go: to stay apart from the integration, to integrate into CIS block  (12 former USSR countries), or to become a member of EU. Only one choice is wise and it was done. Membership in EU was set as the main aim of Latvian foreign policy. To achieve the aim Latvia has to fulfil some criteria. Today Latvia is one of the most real candidates to join EU. In December 1999, during EU summit in Helsinki, the memberstates accepted decision to start with Latvia official negotiations. On February 15, 1999 the negotiations were started. Latvia’s integration process into EU picks up the speed.
Aim of the study
            One of the most important elements of the integration is economic integration of the parts engaged in the process. Economic integration is not possible without trade relations. Trade relations between Latvia and EU countries is the subject of the essay. The aim of the study is to analyse these relations and to determine what elements influence them. To achieve the aim within the analysis we should answer a number of questions: what is the role of EU in trade with Latvia, how does the flows of  import to Latvia from EU and flows of export to EU from Latvia vary in terms of structure, dynamics and proportions.  We will observe the process of Latvia’s transitions from primary export to secondary export. We will figure out if the process of import substitutions in trade between Latvia and EU does take place. The Strömquist and Åberg as well as Johansson and Hacker studies of gravity model will help us to understand the perspectives of further trade relations between the parties as well as the role of link attributes, demand and supply factors in these relations. We will observe if the link between trade and growth in GDP does exist in Latvian case.   
Problem
            As we will see in theoretical outlook there are many theories concerning international trade relations,  but no one of them is completely reliable. Classic theories by Ricardo and Smith as well as Heckscher-Ohlin theory do not explain directions and quantities of trade. Gravity model takes in account these factors, but this model has different formulations and results. The variables in the gravity model are still meter for experimentation.    
Previous studies
There are many both theoretical and empirical studies concerning growth and trade.
As a cornerstone of the theory on trade is Smith and Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantages, which explain importance of trade among nations.  Their theory was emended by Heckscher-Ohlin theory, which includes more factors of  production.  These both theories could be explained by comparison of the relative prices of the commodities in each country in the absence of trade with world prices.
            Gravity model in distinguish with above mentioned theories explains directions and quantities of trade. Strömquist and Åberg as well as Johansson and Hacker  constructed the gravity model for the Baltic Sea area. The results of both the studies among the other conclusions confirmed the importance of regional integration as well.  Strömquist and Åberg  noted that predicted economic growth in Baltic Region will increase trade. Basing on their predictions between 1995-2015 trade could even triple.  
Södersten and Ekholm in their studies stressed, that there is a very strong connection between the growth of real income per capita and growth of real income terms of trade. A close link has been observed in several NIE countries between growth of GDP and growth in income terms of trade. Ceteris paribus, growth in exports will lead to also growth of GDP.
            Empirical analysis of Latvia’s performance in trade relations in conjunction with growth in GDP was observed in different surveys made by European Commission, OECD, World Bank, UN and other international organization as well as by Latvian authorities. 
Outline of the study
Chapter two provides a theoretical outlook the aim of which is to find out answers on two questions: what is the link between growth and trade and why nations should trade. We emphasize on the gravity model in this outlook. The theory observed in the 2nd chapter will succeed empirical analysis, which will be made within chapter three and chapter four. In chapter four we will analyse the role of EU in Latvia’s trade relations as well structure and dynamics of export and import flows between Latvia and EU. In chapter four we will find out correlation between trade and growth in Latvian case. Thus, we will see how does theory comply with practice. Finally, conclusions will end this essay.               

2    Theoretical Outlook: Trade and Growth


The main aim of theory penetration is to find out answers on two fundamental questions understanding of which is a key for the empirical analysis:
u Why nations trade? What they benefit from it?
v What is the link between trade and growth of countries engaged in this trade?
Concerning the first question it should be noted that all the authors (Gillis, Cipher, Mole, Nafziger)  of literature  penetrated emphasize on theory of  comparative advantage formulated by Adam Smith and David Ricardo. The sense of the theory is that world welfare is greatest when each country exports products which comparative (with other world’s countries) costs are lower at home than abroad and imports goods which comparative costs are lower abroad than at home. This theory could  be emended by Heckscher-Ohlin theory, which includes more factors of     production:  a country exports products that use its abundant factors of production more         intensively (abundant factors are cheaper, and thus, the good which uses these factors are cheaper as well) and imports products that require relatively more of its scarce factors (Gillis, 1996).  These both theories could be explained by comparison of the relative prices of the commodities in each country in the absence of trade with world prices. Gillis presents an example: when the home country has comparative advantage (more efficiently, with higher productivity and lower costs) in producing of vegetables, but the rest of world in producing of  computers. As long as the rest of the  world specializes on computers, limited demand of vegetables drives their prices higher than in the home country. From the other hand higher production of computers        compared to the demand drives its prices lower than in the home country.  In terms of trade the home country can export vegetables for higher prices than domestic. At the same time it is  not necessary to produce computers for domestic consumption in inefficient way (with higher costs, lower productivity and inefficient spending of natural resources). Instead of this in terms of trade the home country can shift labour to farming such increasing both production and export as well as country’s welfare. With export of vegetables the home country can then import computers. In such way the  home country has opportunity to benefit from trade and as result improve its      welfare. It must be mentioned that small countries benefit more from trade because the gains are greater the more the pretrade relative price differs from the posttrade world price (Gillis, 1996). At the same time Argentine economist Raul Predisch and Hans Singer of the University of Sussex argued that in long time period prices received for vegetables (as in our case) will fall on world markets relative to the prices of home country’s import of computers from the rest of world. The most used measure of relative prices is Net Barter Terms of Trade (NTT) or Income Terms of Trade (ITT). As soon as we have mentioned these measures it is easily to find link between growth and trade.
As a very important factor which is closely correlated with GDP is Income Terms of Trade. This concept can be defined as the export volume multiplied with Net Barter Terms of Trade or as the volume of exports divided by an impor price index.
Net Barter Terms of Trade can be defined as:
           [2-1]
Where Pe – export price index; Pm – import price index, t – current year, 0 – base year.
ITT can be defined as:
                  [2-2]
Where Px is export price indice, Pm is import price indeice and Qx is volume of exports. There is a very strong connection between the growth   of real income per capita and growth of real income terms of trade. A close link has been observed in several New Industrialised Countries (NIE) countries between growth of GDP and growth in ITT. Ceteris paribus, growth in exports will lead to also growth  of  GDP.
Thus, both volume and price effects are included in the concept. There is a hypothesis that ITT plays a very significant role in growth of GDP of a country (Södersten, Ekholm, 1999). Theory and historical practices show that mostly there is a certain growth of GDP according to growth of trade. Respectively, 1% of growth in GDP creates around 2.5% of growth in trade. We shall attempt to prove this hypothesis basing on Latvia’s growth and trade with the European Union countries.
Above described concept of comparative advantages and Heckscher – Ohlin theory are the most often used one to describe trade among nations. However, these models do not tell us  much about volume and direction of international trade. A gravity-type model of international trade, by contrast, has a feature, that it includes the volume or value and direction of trade (Strömquist and Åberg, 1998). This model is illustrated graphically in figure 1.







Historical background
 

Common border
 
 
                                                                                   


 



Country
”j”
 
Country
(region)
”i”
 
                                                                                               
                                  LINK                             ATTRIBUTES


 



Supply                                                                                                    Demand
Figure 1  Graphical illustration of the gravity model.
Source: Nilsson, 1999
           
The model describes the trade flow  from a particular origin country (region) i  to a particular destination country j. The model is divided as to “mass factors” and link attributes. Three types of factors are included which contribute to a quantitative explanation of the trade flow between any pair of countries:
            p Supply factors. Economic forces at the flow’s origin or source – factors indicating the total potential supply of the exporting country i. The major factor determining potential supply of country i is its capacity of production (), represented by GDP, and the ratio  of its production for export to total production (the “openness ratio”), presented by size of population. As it was proved above GDP varies positively with trade. However, the openness ratio trends to vary negatively with population. Population increasing leads to conditions when country could satisfy its own demand under autarchy.
 p Demand factors. Economic forces at the flow’s destination or sink – factors indicating the total potential demand of the importing country j.
p Link attributes. Economic forces either aiding or resisting the flow’s movement       between countries – these factors reflect trade resistance or transaction costs (link attributes). Transaction costs comprise a great variety of variables, which can be divided into three main   categories: natural impediments (for example sea), artificial obstacles (administrative borders), and affinities (language). Transaction costs are often expressed in terms of geographical distance between certain points within each country. Increasing distance results in higher transaction costs and a decline in trade. One more important factor is market information. We are still better      informed about markets in our neighbourhood than in faraway countries.
The general model has the following form (Strömquist and Åberg, 1998):
  [2-3]      
Where  is the US dollar value of the flow from the country i  to j.                                                                                 
 is the US dollar value of GDP as a measure of supply capacity in i.
 is the US dollar value of GDP as a measure of demand capacity in j.
 represents links attributes between i and j, reflecting various transaction costs of doing     business.
In the empirical part of the essay we will present Strönquist’s and Åberg’s, and, Johansson and Hacker’s searches results in Baltic Sea Region using the gravity model. 
The link between trade and growth could be found using Harrod-Domar   production function as well, according to which there are four sources of growth:
Y = f (K, L, R, A)        [2-4]    
Where  Y - output of national product, K - stock of capital, L - size of labor force, R - natural    resources, A - increases in the productivity or efficiency with which inputs are used. (Gillis, 1996)
It is obviously that increases of each variable in certain sector of national economy leads to increase of GDP – measure of growth of a country. It is important to remember that from microeconomics theory point of view increase in labour force is  efficient only untill certain level. As concerning natural resources there should be a direct link between increasing of share of the resources and efficiency of using them in the process of  production. It is significantly  important for growth in GDP to improve both productivity and efficiency as well as ensure inflow of capital in certain sector of national economy.            
            From another hand national income on expenditure side must be analysed:
Y = C + I + (X – M)           [2-5]
Where Y – national income, C – consumption, I – domestic capital formation or investment,       X – export of goods and services,  M – import of goods and services (Nafziger, 1997). From the sense of theory it is clear that increases in output could be efficient only in terms of high demand on both world and domestic markets. High internal demand is linked with the level of consumers’ welfare and high external demand for the export is linked with level of comparative advantage of exported goods. It is obviously from the penetration of theory that trade could be the engine for increasing of each source of growth, as well as growth lead to the increase in trade.
            Trade is an especially important element of development process for small countries (e.g. Latvia). Nations with larger markets are able to develop a wider range of industries sooner in their development because thay can take advantage of scale economies - larger facilities are able to produce at lower unit costs than small ones (Gillis, 1996). Thus, on the earlier stages of        development as engine of growth could be primary export or import substitution. In empirical analysis we will emphasize on the role of trade in growth of GDP in Latvia.
P Primary export (staple theory of growth) – a country take advantage to export           agricultural products and raw materials. The feature of primary - orientated early industries    countries is export of labour intensive goods produced by simple technologies and import such goods as equipment, intermediate   products from chemical, petroleum, and metals industries (Gillis, 1996). Further development leads to improved factors utilization, expended factor endowments and linkage effects. We would like to emphasize on backward and forward linkages.
            á Backward linkage – growth of one industry stimulate to develop other industry, which uses inputs of first one. The using industry becomes so large that supplying industries can achieve economies of scale of their own. For example, wheat industry in North America  in 19 century created sufficient demand for transportation equipment and farm machinery (Gillis, 1996).
â Forward linkage  occurs in industries that produce goods that became inputs in other industries. For  example, rather than start with automobiles, a country can prefer to start at the other end by setting up a steel mill (Gillis, 1996).
Thus, creation of these linkages could lead to setting up industries and transition from primary-oriented country to manufacturing-oriented country – from long term point of view it is of course much more favourable for the process of development of a country.
            P Import substitution – setting up industries, which can efficiently produce certain  kinds of import goods in such a way successfully competing with[SB1]  importers. At the same time according to the two-way trade practice in most cases it is impossible to completely avoid from import of certain group of goods because of process widening of the assortment.  From other leg import substitution usually leads to capital goods imports (electrical, mechanical, and transport       equipment, machinery and instruments) for producing goods liable to substitution. Such capital goods oriented import positively emphasize developing of the country in way of improving    productivity, quality, infrastructure, lowering production costs and increasing output. Import  substitution can be defined as:     
             [2-6]
Where  - import substitution index,  - import of certain brand (group) of goods and       M – total import (Cypher, 1997). According to the theory the index decreasing in time period       analysed tells us that share of the group of goods in total import decreasing and thus, import    substitution occurs. Here we must mention that in our  opinion we cannot be sure that cause of such decreasing is import substitution as result of enlargement of domestic industry. As the cause of decreasing could be, for example big amount of trade balance deficit (export minus import). This deficit may be financed by borrowing, attracting investments, or receiving grants from abroad. Essentially:
M – X = F          [2-7]
Where F  is a capital import (Nafziger, 1997) . Foreign loans enable a country to spend more than it produces, invest more than it saves, and import more than it exports. Hollis B. Chenery and Alan M. Strout identify three development stages  in which growth proceeds at the highest rate permitted by the reducing limits of such factors: the skill limit, the savings gap (investment minus savings), and the foreign exchange rate. Foreign skills and technology reduce the skill limit,      foreign aid and capital reduce the gap that limits accelerated growth (Niftier, 1997).
In our empirical analysis we will assess the level of primary export and import substitution in Latvia as well as the process of establishment of linkages and trade balance problems.   
As it was already mentioned, import substitution leads to increasing of capital goods     imports. A study of economists indicates that without capital goods imports developing countries run an export surplus (Niftier,  1997). Contemporary industrializing countries effectively using capital inflows from abroad should usually be able to pay back loans with increased output and   productivity.  In another case in long term such deficit could be a cause of default. In next    paragraph described problem also leads to trade balance deficit. 
Nowadays terms of trade also depend on level of trade integration among trade partners,  membership in trade areas. Such trade areas implement practice of protection of memberstates’ internal market using in trade with third countries such instruments as protective tariffs,  import quotas, subsidies and export protection. Of course this impacts negatively the development of third countries. The level of the impact depends on both the shares of the partner and the protected good in  total export. In empirical part of the essay we will present this problem while analysing    Latvia’s export of agricultural products to EU.
Another factor which could negatively emphasize terms of trade is overvalued exchange rate – official exchange rate is to high, for example, in dollars per national currency or to low in national currency per dollar (or another foreign currency) to balance the importers’ demand for foreign exchange with the exporters’ supply of foreign exchange without high protective tariffs, import quotas, and restrictions on other foreign exchange transactions (Gillis, 1996). Thus,   overvalued exchange rate discourages exports and encourages imports. In empirical part we will find out if the exchange rate of Lats is favourable for Latvian export or not. Sometimes exchange rate becomes overvalued also as a result of a boom in primary exports,  which causes appreciation of the real exchange rate (national currency becomes worth more in foreign currency than before). The most used example of this is Dutch disease. Natural gas export boom and the balance of payments surplus during the 1970s led to rising inflation, declining export of manufactures, lower rates of income growth, and rising unemployment. This paradox can be explained as follows. First, the influx of foreign currency from higher export earnings creates a surplus of this currency  which trends to drive down its price in domestic currency. This shift in supply causes the currency to appreciate in value. Second, higher income from booming primary export also spurs faster domestic inflation, because the additional incomes creates greater demand for all goods and  services in the economy (Gillis, 1996).
For the future empirical analysis it is important to understand why developed countries with enhanced resources (for example wood) prefer to import it from developing countries       instead using own wood. The main explanation is concerned with the value of time. It is obviously that benefits and costs realized in the future have less present value than those that are realized immediately. If the discount rate (the real interest rate) is r percent per year, then in any future year n, the present value placed on resource flows (PV) is:
                  [2-8]
In developing countries the real discount rate is rather higher than in developed countries. Thus, developed countries, because of low discount rate, expect that in future increasing in prices for the resource will exceed discount rate and so these countries will be able to gain more than at present. For developing countries such expectation is quite unreal. The second reason why       developed countries preserve their resources is that these countries take care about ecology and future generations much more.
           Concluding theoretical outlook we would like to mention these indicators, which as well as already noted ones, will be used in the empirical analysis.
            Analysing structure of trade we will calculate:
ˆ Share of total export and import as well as certain group of import and export goods in GDP.
ˆ Share of certain group of export and import goods in total export and import.
ˆ Share of certain group of export and import goods in total trade turnover.
ˆ Share of trade surplus or deficit in total trade turnover.
ˆ Share of two-way trade calculated as value of two way trade divided by total value of trade. 
Within the analysis of “quality” of trade such indicators will be presented:
ˆ export and import value per ton calculated respectively as export and import divided by   quantity of goods exported or imported.
            The following analysis also will present structure of  Latvia’s trade partners by regions and EU countries.

            Thus, theory presented in this chapter should be considered as the tools for the following empirical analysis.

3    Latvia and EU: Trade Relations

3.1 Trade of Latvia by groups of countries

            First of all implementing empirical analysis of trade relations between Latvia and EU it is important to find out the role of EU in Latvian trade activities. In figures 2 and 3 we will      overview the share of Latvian export to EU and the share of EU import to Latvia.
  
Source:  Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, 2000

From the figure 2 it is clear that EU is the major buyer of Latvian export starting with 1995. The share of Latvian export to EU over the period observed increased almost twice. We could explain this as follows. Firstly, the main aim of Latvian foreign policy is to join the EU. This target asks for the integration process, especially economic integration, which leads to much more active trade relations between the parties, engaged in the process. We can prove this statement also by figures placed in appendix 1, which shows that the similar with Latvia tendencies regarding EU share in export exist in all EU membership candidate states. Furthermore, less share of exports to EU in total export than in Latvia exists only in Lithuania, Bulgaria, Slovakia and Turkey. It is obvious that the process of Latvia’s integration into EU picks up speed. Secondly, Latvia’s development processes demands capital goods for  industrialization. Theory shows and practice proves that the suppliers of capital goods  are developed countries, which are specialized on their producing. Thirdly, from the figure 2 we can see that rapid increasing of share of Latvian export to EU started in 1997. It is the time when crisis in Russia (former major buyer of Latvian export) occurred. Purchasing power and as result demand decreased sharply in Russia. From the figure 2 follows that sharp increasing of Latvian export to EU accompanies with sharp decreasing of Latvian export to CIS. Thus, crisis in Russia is the  engine of Latvian trade reorientation “from east to west”. Figure 2 also indicates increasing of Latvian export to other countries and to the Latvia’s neighbours – Estonia and Lithuania.  Thus, in 1999 share of Latvian export to CIS (mainly to Russia) was less than that one  to Estonia and Lithuania. In our opinion it is good example when such link attributes as common border, distance and language (most Latvians speak Russian) stop to work. However, negative historical background exists between the countries (Soviet occupation).     
 Now we will overview the dynamics of the share of EU’s import to Latvia.
       
Source:  Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, 2000

            From figure 3 we can find out similar trends as from figure 2: EU is the major          importer of its goods to Latvia. The share over the period observed increased more than twice. However, contrary to Latvian export tends, the most rapid increasing occurred on the earlier stage of Latvia’s developing. We can explain it so. Every company must be  aimed on “conquering” of new markets, niches. Strong companies from developed countries have more opportunities to do this. As soon as Latvian market was liberalized it was “conquered” by  EU’s  importers. Also in 1994 market protection mechanisms were not yet established. Here is one more explanation: on earlier stage of developing a country needs for much more capital goods than on the latter ones. In each case import structure should be analysed – it will be done latter. From 1996 the import from EU grows 2-4% on average annually. This growth occurs as result of division of      decreasing CIS’s import share between EU and other countries. As in the case with export, the similar with Latvia tendencies concerning EU’s import share in total import exist in all candidate states (see appendix 1). 
            To understand the cause of such strong trade relations between Latvia and EU we should deep our analysis and find out which EU countries are the main Latvia’s trade partners.
As we can see from table 1 Latvia’s export to Germany, Sweden and Great Britain     compiles about half of total export. The share of export to each country increases over the period observed, especially to Great Britain. Absolute value of export to Great Britain increases sharply as well, while in Sweden case it declines.
Table  1. The main Latvia’s export partners in EU over the period 1998, 1999                    and January, 2000
Country
   Value,  Ths. Lats
    Share,  %


1998
1999
2000-Jan
1998
1999
2000-Jan
Germany
166822
169984
14845
15.6
16.9
18.6
Great Britain
144343
165838
13746
13.5
16.4
17.3
Sweden
110017
107621
9916
10.3
10.7
12.5
Source: Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, 2000
As we can see from table 2 the import from three major partners compiles about 1/3 of total import to Latvia. The share and absolute value of import from Germany and Finland tends to decline, while import from Sweden in January, 2000 increased. 
Table  2. The main Latvia’s import partners in EU over the period 1998, 1999                    and January, 2000
Country
   Value,  Ths. Lats
    Share,  %


1998
1999
2000-Jan
1998
1999
2000-Jan
Germany
315547
261297
15982
16.8
15.2
13.3
Finland
179189
156876
12890
9.5
9.1
10.7
Sweden
135096
124847
10833
7.2
7.2
9.0
Source: Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, 2000
Thus, Latvia’s major both import and export partners are Germany and Sweden. If we compare figures in table 1 and table 2 we can see that value of Germany’s and Sweden’s import is much higher than value of Latvian export to these countries (Latvia has trade deficit with Sweden and Germany). However, share of Latvia’s export to both the countries is higher than their share of import to Latvia.
This analysis could be extended by overview of Latvian export share in total import to EU and Latvian export main partners – Germany, Sweden and UK.
Table 3. Share of  Latvia’s export in total import to EU over the period 1993-1998 and its memberstates over the period 1996-1998, (%)

1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
EU
0.063
0.115
0.163
0.187
0.198
0.248
Germany
0.036
0.041
0.47
Sweden
0.113
0.167
0.217
UK
 …
… 
0.45
0.61
0.63
Source: Eurostat, 1999; Direction of Trade, 1998
It is obviously that share of Latvian export in total import of EU and its memberstates cannot be large. The most important conclusion we can find out from table 3 is that the share has tend to increase. Figures placed in appendix 2 shows that among the candidate states only the shares of Poland, Czech Republics and Turkey in extra-EU trade are expressed in full per cent.     
The next step of our analysis is to find out why EU countries, especially Germany and Sweden, are so important Latvia’s trade partners. To answer these question link attributes and results of Strömquist and Åberg’s, and Johansson and Hacker’s studies of gravity model for the Baltic region should  be    analysed. The gravity model was estimated on cross-section data where  flows within the Baltic Sea region and additional flows to the other countries outside the area were included. Strömquist and Åberg used such a formula:
[3-1]
Where  is country’s i export to j , measured in million 1995 USD; GDP in country i (j) , is measured using level of 1995 (USD);  is the airflight distance between the capitals of the countries; EU is a dummy variable, where 1 indicates membership in EU and 0 otherwise; CEFTA (Central European Free Trade Area) is another dummy variable; I denotes pairs of countries dependent on sea borne transport;  are parameters representing income elasticity (Strömquist and Åberg, 1998). GDP and distance are common variables for the gravity model. Other ones are the subject for experimentation. Johansson and Hacker beside GDP and distance used such variables as common border, situations when both the partners are inter                   mature-countries, Poland and M-country, inter Nordic, inter emergency-Baltic, Baltic-Nordic and Estonia, Latvia or Lithuania, as well as intercept variable (Johansson and Hacker, the materials on the course “European Economic Integration”).  
Some results of the studies  are showed in table 4. Coefficients indicate how each variable  impact flows, and trade-value indicates variables impact trade turnover. Income has relatively high positive values for its coefficient estimates, which indicates a strong income effect on trade. Higher income leads to higher demand and supply and thus to increasing of trade flows and turnover. The  income effect on trade is stronger according to Johansson and Åberg’s studies.





Table 4. Selected Results of the estimated gravity model in the Strömquist’s and Åberg’s and Johansson’s and Hacker’s studies.
Variable
                            Coefficient
                           T-value

Johansson & Hacker
Strömquist & Åberg
Johansson & Hacker
Strömquist & Åberg
GDP, importer
0.74
0.61
30.5
14.18
GDP, exporter
0.83
0.67
34.2
15.51
Distance
-0.87
-0.00115
-14.3
-7.85
Common border
0.38
X
3.3
X
EU
X
1.06
X
4.67
Inter M-countries
1.46
X
16.0
X
Inter Nordic
0.61
X
3.8
X
Inter E-baltic
1.47
X
7.8
X
Baltic-Nordic-ELL
0.97
X
5.4
X
Source: Strömquist and Åberg, 1998; Johansson and Hacker, 2000
However, the studies gave different results concerning effect of distance on trade. The importance of distance is not so extensive in Strömquist and Åberg’s model: if the distance increases by the kilometre, trade flows will diminish with 0.1 per cent.  This result could  explain that relatively long distance between Riga and London is not important limitation factor for Latvia to export relatively large share of its export to Great Britain, wile both Latvian export to Sweden and Finland’s and Germany’s import to Latvia declining.  But at the same time according to Johansson and Hacker’s results distance has even stronger negative effect on trade than positive effect of income for exporter. Common border has not very strong effect in their study. 
We suppose that the most important result of the studies for understanding of the aim of the essay is that the results of both of the studies confirm  the importance of regional integration. Especially we would like emphasize on straight of EU factor.
            The fact, that Latvia, Sweden and Germany are  Baltic-Nordic – ELL countries has quite strong positive effect on trade as well.
            To understand importance of Latvia’s trade with Sweden and Germany such link attributes as artificial obstacles, natural impediments, language similarities, historical background should be analysed. Latvia, Sweden and Germany are The Baltic Sea countries, this factor of course is positive. Short distance between Latvia and Sweden gives us the right to state that our countries are neighbours, despite the fact that we don’t have a common border. Both Sweden and Germany have strong historical links to Latvia. The Vikings raided the country and German crusaders invaded the territory and governed  it for two centuries. Concerning language similarities while  studying Swedish we noted that there are many similar words in Latvian and Swedish.
            Strömquist’s and Åberg, and Johansson’s and Hacker models allow to see that the potential to extend trade relations still exists. Concerning Latvia and Sweden the results is quite similar: the  share of Latvian export to Sweden could be larger, while Sweden import to Latvia is almost optimal. Regarding Latvia and Germany the results differ. Johansson and Hacker suppose that these trade relations are almost optimal, while Strömquist and Åberg consider that the relations are far from predicted.      
Table 5. Relative gap (1-P/O)  between observed and model-predicted trade flows         between Latvia-Sweden and Latvia-Germany, (%)

                           Sweden
                   Germany

Johansson & Hacker
Strömquist & Åberg
Johansson & Hacker
Strömquist & Åberg
Exporter
-0.01
-0.04
-0.07
-0.71
Importer
-0.25
-0.19
0.01
-0.66
Source: Nilsson, 1999; Johansson and Hacker
            Thus, EU and its members, especially Sweden and Germany play significantly important role in Latvia’s trade relations. There are all prerequisites to proceed developing of trade relations  because of Latvia’s integration into EU and existing of favourable link attributes for trade relations with Sweden, Germany and other EU members.

3.2 The analysis of the structure of Latvian export and import

            Before analysing the structure of Latvian export and import by commodities we would like to present total data on export and import calculated using the formulas described in the theoretical outlook. Table 6 data shows that the share (% from GDP) of Latvian export to EU in ling term has tend to increase, while the share of total export decreasing. This fact one more time confirms that the process of gradual Latvian export reorientation from Russian market to EU markets takes place. Comparing table 6 data with figure 2 data we can see that in 1999 comparing with 1998, share of Latvian export to EU in total export increased, while the share in GDP decreased. This can be explained in such a way: in 1999 comparing with 1998 value of Latvian export to EU decreased by 0.3%, while value of the export to CIS decreased by 7%. Thus, share of the export to EU in total export increased. At the same time GDP in 1999 increased by 0.5%. Thus, share of the export in GDP decreased, because value of GDP increased, while value of export to EU decreased  (Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, 2000).       
Table 6. Share of  Latvian export and import in GDP and total trade turnover over the time period 1995-1999

1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Total export, % of GDP
30.7
29.0
32.6
31.5
27.5
Export to EU, % of GDP
12.9
12.6
14.5
16.9
16.5
Total import, % of GDP
43.8
44.5
47.7
49.1
47.1
Import from EU, % of GDP
20.4
22.3
25.7
29.0
25.7
Total trade balance, % of GDP
-13.0
-15.5
-15.1
-17.6
-19.5
Trade balance with EU, % of GDP
-7.5
-9.5
-11.2
-12.1
-9.2
Share of total trade deficit in turnover, %
16.5
23.3
24.0
27.5
26.2
Share of trade with EU deficit in turnover, %
52.0
56.5
53.8
51.4
48.1
Source: Calculated using Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia data
The shares of total import and import from EU have the same tends, but decreasing of the share of import from EU is more sharp. However, in 1999 both shares have decreased. We can try to explain this. We suppose that it happened due to decreasing in demand, which occurred as result of decreasing in people’s income. We consider that in short-term period reorientation of export has also negative aspect: it takes time to find new markets and to adapt their “rules of game”. The reorientation asks for modernization of industry, sometimes for changes in assortment of export production. Many factories in Latvia practice so called “extra-holydays” tactic for their workers. Very often it  is one or even two month long. As result workers wages decrease.
In fact, being a non-member state, it is quite difficult for Latvia to export its commodities to EU. First of all, each certain exporter should have special licence on quality issued by EU authorities. Of course, besides above described negative short-term factor, it has long-term positive aspect: industry modernization, quality improving, costs and price lowering. Especially strict requirements regarding Latvian export have food products exporter. Besides quality requirements EU also exercises quota policy for non-member states exporters. First of all it is applicable for agricultural products. It is known that in EU exists agricultural products surplus. Thus, EU exercises not only quota policy for imports of such products, but also export subsidies policy. These facts one more time underline the importance of Latvia’s membership in EU, when limitations will be abolished and Latvia will be able enjoy the same trade conditions as all EU members and then Latvian agricultural products will be “the head ache” of EU. According to Strömquit and Åberg estimation we can expect the significant growth of trade flows  when Latvia will join EU.  
The most important achievement in bilateral relations with the EC was The Agreement On Free Trade And Trade-Related Matters, which entered into force on January 1, 1995. The restrictions on import and export of industrial products were  eliminated in  January 1995 (Europe Agreement between The EC and Republic of Latvia, Art. 10 and 11). For agricultural and food products, the Agreement provides for reciprocal trade concessions. The broad-ranging Association Agreement between the EU and each of the Baltic States, concluded on June 9, 1995, entered into force on February 12, 1998. Since July 1996, these trade agreements have been modified to take into account the Agreement on Agriculture concluded during the GATT Uruguay Round, and also to reflect further improvements in the concessions on agricultural products granted to the Baltic States by the Community. In the Marrakech agreement, the EC replaced the variable agricultural levies and other non-tariff barriers by fixed customs duties from July 1, 1995. This replacement effected the agricultural concession granted in the Free Trade Agreements with the Baltic  States, and in order to maintain the degree of preferential access granted, it was therefore necessary to adjust the agricultural concessions provided in the Agreements on free trade and trade-related matters. In 1997, trade in processed   products was even further liberalised. At the same time allocated quotas of dairy products were slightly extended and exports of confectionery and spirits to the EU were possible on more favourable terms. The GATT-related adjustments, together with the new concessions decided by the EC, resulted in the level of preference for all agricultural products being increased from 60 to 80%. The applicable duty is in general 20% of the MFN duty (compared to 40% previously). The arrangements also provide for a 5% yearly increase in the volumes of the tariff quotas. Concerning the EC imports of agricultural products to Latvia, there are no quotas, but the rates of the customs duties vary from 0 to 20% (Europe Agreement, 1995).
One more factor, which limits export and is favourable for import is high national currency (Lats) rate towards foreign currencies. For example, 1 USD costs 0.59 Lats. This rate is stable since 1993. Thus, export is expensive and import is cheap. Latvian government suppose that devaluations of Lats from long-term point of view will have negative effect.
The surplus of EU import to Latvia over Latvian export to EU best of all can be described by such indicator as share of trade deficit in trade turnover (see table 6). The deficit compiles a half of trade turnover between Latvia and EU, and it twice exceeds the share of total deficit in total turnover. This fact also shows the superiority of EU’s import flows over the flows from other countries. Such deficit occurred due to factors described above as well as factors which will be described  in the next paragraphs. The most importance ones are low competition ability of Latvian products, limited access to EU markets and high demand for import of technological equipments.        
Thus, also partly due to above mentioned negative factors Latvia has such huge trade deficit, especially with EU (see table 6). It is a number of  factors apart from above mentioned, which explain causes of current account deficit in Latvia. For example growth of deficit in the current account in 1998 was predetermined by two main factors: drastic lowering of external demand and growth of imports in private consumption (Ministry of Economy of Latvia, 1999).
The deficit in the current account is created when the domestic demand goes up faster that GDP. This means that the internal saving – investment balance continually goes down. Increasingly bigger share of foreign saving is used to cover investment. Such process when the domestic demand goes up faster than GDP is typical of almost all countries in transition.
Data of the table placed in the appendix 3 shows that in 1998 all candidate states had deficit in trade with EU. This basically is determined, on the one hand, by the objective need to restructure production requiring an accelerated process of investing and consequently the domestic savings may turn out to be too small to take care of this process. On the other hand, the active privatisation ensures attraction of foreign resources to economy mainly in the form of foreign direct investments. From this perspective, growth of deficit in the current account is fully justified and it should not result in far-reaching negative consequences for the equilibrium in the external sector since with time investments create the opportunities for faster growth of GDP. Yet, in Latvia the reduction of the domestic saving – investment balance was influenced not only by the speedy growth of investments but also by the decrease of saving (see Figure 4).
As seen in Figure 4 growth of deficit in the current account in 1997 was mainly caused by the fast growth of investment and in 1998 – to a greater extent by reduction of savings. Reduction of saving in 1998 was mainly linked with the narrowing of exports due to the    Russian crisis at the end of the year considerably declining industrial output.



*Estimation of the Ministry of Economy.
Figure 4. Current Account, Investment and Saving , (% of GDP)
Source: Ministry of Economy of Latvia, Reports, 1998, 1999

            As it was explained in theoretical overview the deficit of current account should be covered by capital inflow, thus making balance of payments (current account is a part of balance of payments) positive. The balance of payments of Latvia since the beginning of 1990s is positive that is foreign assets of the Bank of Latvia is going up. This means that the incoming financial flows into Latvia are bigger than outgoing. Balance of payments in Latvia is presented in the appendix 4.  Analysis of the accounts of the balance of payments of Latvia show that there are certain typical trends retained for already several years. Balance of the current account from clearly positive at the beginning of 1990s turned into expressly negative in 1996-1998. Balance of the financial and capital account during the same period stayed positive and fully offset the negative balance of the current account. However capital flows keep reducing with every year. Moreover, the structure of the incoming capital changes. One the one hand – the share of short term capital flows go up in the structure of net capital flows, on the other hand – the debt forming part of flows goes up. The mentioned trends caused deterioration of the basic balance (the current account of the balance of payments and the net balance of long term capital).
Lessening of saving may also be caused by the excessive growth of imports when domestically made products due to their low competitiveness are ousted out from the domestic market by foreign goods. In that case import of consumer and intermediate consumer goods grow faster than private consumption and output of goods and services. Then it may happen (in the absence of the corresponding growth of export of goods) that not only investments but also current consumption is financed from foreign saving. This phenomenon was observed in 1998  in Latvia when private consumption went up by 10.6% yet import of consumer goods – by 26.9%. In this case, with the narrowing of the markets of domestic products also the potential output goes down. As a result also the GDP becomes smaller and finally also savings, in turn stimulating growth of the deficit in the current account (Ministry of Economy of Latvia, 1999, December).
As mentioned above the deficit in the current account is quite normal for transition economies. The reduction of the deficit in the current account of the balance of payments of Latvia will mainly depend on how fast Latvia succeeds to restructure industry and increase competitiveness of Latvian producers both in the domestic and external markets. This process requires a certain period of time. At present, one of the main tasks of economic policy is to offset deficit with such capital flows that minimize risk of fast change of these flows. To preserve the equilibrium between the deficit of the current account and the flows of incoming capital measures of fiscal, monetary and structural policy should be co-ordinated. Not less important than attraction of external resources is efficient use of these resources. Therefore structural policy plays a decisive role to maintain the balance of payments in equilibrium in the long run.
The deficit in trade as well can be explained by the low value per ton of export (because it is mainly raw materials and other low-value goods) and high value per ton of import (because it is mainly capital goods and knowledge-intensive goods). Table 7 presents export values per ton in countries of The Baltic Sea Region.
   Table 7 data proves above mentioned statement: export value in industrialized countries is much higher than for example, in Latvia, Estonia and Poland. Such low export value in Norway can be explained by low oil prices – the main product of Norwegian export.   





Table 7. Export value in ECU per ton, mid 90’s
Country
ECU per ton
Switzerland
5850
Germany
1900
France
1260
Portugal
1009
United Kingdom
950
Sweden
810
Finland
720
Belgium-Luxemburg
650
Netherlands
420
Latvia
220
Poland
210
Norway
170
Estonia
140
Source: Strömquist and Åberg, 2000
Now  we  will   present   the   analysis  of  Latvian  export and import by groups of commodities.
The analysis gave us the results as we expected. These results are common for developing countries: they export their abundant  natural resources and import capital goods. In Latvia this abundant resource is wood. Forests cover 45% of the territory. From the appendices 5 and 8 data we can see that in 1998 the share of export of wood and wood products  in total export compiled 46% and about 20% in total trade turnover. In 1992 the shares compiled relatively 1.87% and 1%. The share of wood export in GDP increased 25 times over the period 1992-1998 (see appendix 7). Thus, awareness of the comparative advantage led to impressive growth of the share. However, example with wood export characterizes quite slow process of transition from primary export to secondary one. Wood is exported mainly in unwrought condition. Furthermore, while wood export is growing impressively the growth of paper products import from EU is occurring as well (see appendix 6). The share of paper products import in total import tripled, but the share of such import in GDP increased ten times the amount. Finally, the share of two-way trade is only 4% (see appendix 9). Thus, forward links in this sector are not set up yet in Latvia. 
Latvia also is relatively rich with such mineral resources as sand, clay and stone, but not so much as with forests. As results the export share decreased in total export (from 78% to 21%), in total trade turnover (from 57% to 9%), in turnover of this group of commodities (from 99% to 71%) as well as in GDP (from 19% to 5%). However, mineral products form  the second largest share of Latvian export.
The third largest share belongs to textile and textile products. This labour-intensive industry is traditional for Latvia. The share of such export increased from 2% to 12% in total export, from 1% to 5% in total turnover, from 57% to 60% in turnover of the group, and from 0,4% to 3% in GDP.
As we expected Latvia mainly imports from EU capital goods. Import of machinery and electrical equipment increased from 17% to 25% in total import, from 1% to 7% in GDP, from 4% to 14% in total trade turnover. The share in the turnover of this group compiles about 95%.
The similar tendencies we can see analysing the second largest group of import – vehicles (the figures relatively are 13%-14%, 0.8%-4%, 2%-7% and 97%).
Besides the capital goods, EU exports to Latvia  quite large amount of products of  chemical industry. The share of such import has increasing dynamics as well: from 5% to 10% in total import, from 0.5% to 3% in GDP, from 1% to 6% in total trade turnover and from 50% to 90% in the turnover of the group.
Analysing data we can see that in 1998 Latvian wood export share is almost equal with the share of capital good import.
In our opinion the proportion between export and import flows of certain group of commodities best of all can be described by such indicator as share of two-way trade. As we expected the level of two-way trade for the main import and export goods is low. It is common for trade relations between industrialized country and developing countries: export flows compile mainly natural resources and labour-intensive goods, while import flows compile mainly capital goods. This theory can be as well proved on Latvian example: the share of two-way trade for wood is 4%, for machinery and electrical equipment – 10%, for vehicles – 6%. However, the level is very high for textile and mineral products. In our opinion it could be explain by large diversity of the goods within the group. In the group of mineral products Latvia exports mainly sand and stone, but imports mineral fuels and oils. The high two-way trade level within textile goods group can be explained by large assortment of such goods.
Specific situation occurred regarding such industries as chemical (with decreasing of the two-way trade level from 98% to 20% over the period 1992-1998), leather (with increasing from 15% to 80%), plastic and rubber (with decreasing from 80% to 17%), footwear (with decreasing from 92% to 57%), metallurgical industries (with increasing from 9% to 96%). In our opinion it could be explained as follows. Latvia has specific historic-economical  background. Being a part of the USSR, Latvia was highly industrialized part of it. Soviet Union implemented the policy of setting up plant and factories in Latvia. The policy was based not on principles of economics, but as a part of politics. As a result factories produced their goods using raw materials and spare parts delivered from hundreds places within the large USSR. As a result of dissolution  of the Soviet Union these relations between producers and the delivers of input resources gradually (1992-1995) was destroyed. The hard process of searching for new origins of raw materials, new markets for their goods as well as the process of industry restructuring, competitiveness improving  for Latvian industries was started. Some of them (metallurgical, leather industries) deal with this quite successfully, while another (chemical, plastic and rubber, footwear industries) still try to find salvation for their problems. As a result the shares of export of their products in total and group export, turnover and GDP fluctuate.
Specific situation occurs with food products as well. For export of agricultural products EU implements quota policy, while Latvian market for EU import is opened. Despite this fact the level of two way trade for vegetable products increased from 0.41% to 17% over the period 1992-1999. The share of vegetable products in total export increased from 0.02% to 0.26%, in GDP from 0.01% to 0.36%, in total turnover from 0.02% to 0.11%, in the turnover of this group from 0.21% to 8.5%, while these shares for EU import decreased.
The shares increasing for both the partners in trade with live animals and animal products is observed
Concerning food industries products the level of two-way trade increased from 8% in 1993 to 13% in 1998. Latvian export share in trade turnover of the group increased from 4% to 6%.
In our opinion the increasing of Latvian food export accompanies with yearly increasing of quotas for the Latvian import.  It was already mentioned that each Latvian food exporter should get special quality licence issued by EU authority. We suppose that Latvian food industry is quite developed and produces qualitative products. Some of them (Riga’s Black Balsam and green cheese) have no analogues in the world.  We consider that the process of Latvian integration into EU will lead to increasing of Latvian food export.
           

4    Trade and Growth in Latvia


The aim of this chapter is to find out how does the theory about close link between both growth in GDP and trade complies with Latvian reality. Empirical researches in countries all over the world show that 2.5% growth in trade gives 1% growth in GDP. In table 8 we will compare growths in GDP and trade in Latvia as well we will extend our analysis by such GDP expenditure elements as individual and national consumption and capital formation.
Table 8. Growth in GDP and growth in trade in Latvia over the period 1994-1999

1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Growth in GDP
2.2
-1.6
3.3
8.6
3.6
0.1
Growth in total trade turnover
-5.1
32.1
25.8
23.2
15.5
-7.4
Growth in trade turnover with EU
26.6
56.3
25.7
33.6
25.0
-1.0
Growth in total export
-18.4
24.4
15.5
22.2
10.0
-5.7
Growth in export to EU
-3.2
40.3
18.1
33.1
28.0
6.0
Growth in total import
8.7
38.2
33.2
23.8
18.9
-8.4
Growth in import from EU
65.0
68.5
30.5
33.9
23.4
-5.1
Individual consumption
0.2
0.6
10.3
5.0
5.8
1.0
National consumption
4.7
7.7
1.8
0.3
5.3
1.6
Forming of capital
4.9
8.7
22.3
20.7
11.1
5.1
Source: Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, 2000; Statistics Yearbooks of Latvia, 1998
As we can see the direct link between growth in trade and growth in GDP exists only in 1996-1998. Also we can note  that there is not a strict proportion between growth in trade and GDP. Analysing growth in trade with EU and total growth in trade it is clear that trade  turnover, export and import between Latvia and EU grew much faster than the total one, as well as decreasing in 1995 and 1999 is much less. Situation in 1995 shows that all indicators including consumption and forming of  capital increases, while GDP decreases. To explain this we should take in account Harrod-Domar production function according to which there are four sources of growth: K - stock of capital, L - size of labour force, R - natural  resources, A - increases in the productivity or efficiency with which inputs are used (Gillis, 1996). Besides above mentioned factors also these ones impact GDP growth. We suppose that in 1995 these  four factors emphasized GDP increasing.
Furthermore, Latvian statistical data does not prove the theory that there is a direct link between the growth of GDP and the growth of net barter terms of trade. If ITT in 1995 =100, then in 1996 it is 92, in 1997 – 90, in 1998 – 93 (World Bank, 2000). Thus,  ITT declined, but as we have seen above GDP grew in Latvia over this period.
Thus, we cannot find strong direct correlation between growth in trade and growth in GDP in Latvia. However, it is obviously that trade growth positively impacts growth of GDP. Differences in tends can occur only as result of strong negative impact  from the side of other factors which influence GDP. We did not find direct link between growth of GDP and growth of ITT in Latvia.

5    Conclusion


The empirical analysis showed the tend of permanent increasing of both EU’s import to Latvia and Latvian export to EU, while Russian share rapidly decreased. Thus, trade reorientation from east to west, which complies with the process of Latvia’s integration into EU, takes place.
Empirical analysis complies with theory: as it is common for developing countries Latvian export mainly consists of primary export (raw materials, mainly wood), while it imports from EU mainly capital goods. EU exercises significant surplus in trade with Latvia. It is explainable by number of factors: low competition ability of Latvian export, limited access to EU markets, low Latvian export value per ton, industry restructuring process asks for time, as well asks for time  the process of entering to new markets and adaptation to requirements of these markets, Latvian export non-stimulating national currency rate.
In our opinion the process of transition from primary export to secondary export is quite slow. The main element of Latvian primary export – wood mainly - is exported in unwrought condition. The process of setting up of industries, which use wood as input, does not take place. At the same time share of imported paper products is growing. Thus, the process of import substitution is slow also.
Empirical analysis showed that there is not a strong direct link between growth in trade and growth in GDP in Latvia because of strong influence from the side of other factors. However, no doubt trade positively impacts growth
The studies of the gravity model for The Baltic Sea region show that Latvia does not use all its potential in trade relations. Latvia has favourable link attributes (especially with Sweden and Germany) for the extending of trade relations. According to  the Strömquist and Åberg study the process of Latvia’s integration into EU is significantly important.
References
Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, (www.csb.lv)
Central Statistical Bureau of Latvia, Statistics Yearbook 1998
Comext, CD Database
Cypher, J.M., Dietz, J.L., (1997), The Process of Economic Development, Routledge, London
                   The Economist Intelligence Unit, (1999), The Baltic States, EIU Country Report
Ekholm, K., Södersten, B., (1999), Growth and Trade vs Trade and growth
Eurostat, (2000), EU Enlargement: Key Data On Candidate Countries
                   Europe Agreement Between Latvia and The EC, (1995)
Gillis, M., Perkins, Roemer, Snodgrass, (1996), Economics of Development, 4th ed., Norton, New York
IMF, (1998), Directions of Trade, Statistics Yearbook.
Johansson, B., Hacker, S. The Gravity Model For The Baltic Sea Region, Material on course    European Economic Integration
Mole, W., (1997), The Economics of European Integration – Theory, Practice, Policy, 3rd ed., Aldershot: Ashgate
Ministry of Economy of Latvia, (1998, December), Economic Development of Latvia, Report
Ministry of Economy of Latvia, (1999, June), Economic Development of Latvia, Report
Ministry of Economy of Latvia, (1999, December), Economic Development of Latvia, Report
Nafziger, E.W., (1997), The Economics of Developing Countries, 3rd ed., Prentice Hall
Nilsson, D., (1999), Modelling Aggregate Trade Between Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania and Sweden, Master Thesis
Strömquist, U., Åberg, P., (1998), Trade and Modal Change in The Baltic Region: Scenarios to 2015,    Division of Regional Planning
World Bank, (1999), Latvia at Glance

  



6    Appendices

Appendix 1
External trade, 1998

Bulgaria
Cyprus
Czech Rep
Estonia
Hungary
Latvia
Lithuania
EU share of total imports (%)
45.0
61.9
63.3
60.1
64.1
55.3
50.2
EU share of total exports (%)
49.7
50.4
64.2
55.1
72.9
56.6
38.0


Malta
Poland
Romania
Slovakia
Slovenia
Turkey

EU share of total imports (%)
69.3
65.9
57.7
50.4
69.4
52.4


EU share of total exports (%)
52.8
68.3
64.5
55.8
65.5
50.0

Source: Eurostat
Appendix 2
Candidate country share of total extra-EU trade, %, 1998

Bulgaria
Cyprus
Czech Rep
Estonia
Hungary
Latvia
Lithuania
Candidate country share of total extra-EU trade
0.3
0.2
2.2
0.3
2.2
0.2
0.3

Malta
Poland
Romania
Slovakia
Slovenia
Turkey

Candidate country share of total extra-EU trade
0.2
3.1
0.8
0.8

0.8
2.5

Source: Eurostat







Appendix 3
Balance of trade with EU, Mio ECU,  1998

Bulgaria
Cyprus
Czech Rep
Estonia
Hungary
Latvia
Lithuania
Balance of trade
-607
-2354
-2198
-1376
-2409
-1232
-1858

Malta
Poland
Romania
Slovakia
Slovenia
Turkey
EU15
Balance of trade
-742
-16792
-3154
-2045
-936
-16359
+19200
Source: Eurostat

Appendix 4
Balance of Payments of Latvia
(% of GDP)
 
1998
1999
1996
1997
1998

I
II
III
IV
I
II



A. Current account
-5.7
-7.8
-13.0
-17.2
-8.1
-9.6
-5.5
-6.1
-11.1
Trade balance
-13.1
-16.7
-18.5
-21.8
-11.6
-14.6
-15.6
-15.1
-17.6
Exports
34.9
34.0
30.0
27.3
30.1
29.5
29.0
32.6
31.5
Imports
48.0
50.7
48.5
49.1
41.7
44.1
44.5
47.7
49.1
Non-factorial services, net
6.7
5.9
2.7
2.4
4.3
4.0
7.5
6.6
4.4
Factorial services, net
-0.4
1.7
1.4
0.5
-2.1
0.1
0.8
1.0
0.8
Transfers, net
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.6
1.3
0.8
1.8
1.4
1.3
B. Long term capital, net
8.1
12.1
4.8
5.8
4.9
14.7
8.5
12.3
7.7
Basic balance (A + B)
2.5
4.3
-8.2
-11.4
-3.2
5.1
3.1
6.2
-3.4
C. Short term capital, net
0.0
-4.6
2.2
9.3
2.6
2.4
2.0
-5.9
1.8
D. Net errors and omissions
0.6
7.1
1.2
1.2
3.6
2.3
-0.9
1.6
2.6
Total balance (A + B + C + D)
3.1
6.8
-4.8
-0.9
3.0
9.8
4.1
1.8
1.0
Source: Economic Development of Latvia, Report, December 1999











 [SB1]m

Nav komentāru:

Ierakstīt komentāru